Welfare

Thor and the Nordic welfare state: Not so Nordic, after all


SUGGESTED

Economic Theory
When the action movie ‘Thor’ and its sequel were shown in cinemas, the media often referred to its protagonist as a ‘Viking God’ or an ‘ancient Scandinavian God’. Call me a pedant, but as someone who devoured the old sagas as a child, I take issue with that. The Scandinavians have no monopoly claim on the ‘Thor’ figure. They don’t even have a preferential claim. ‘Thor’ was a pan-Germanic deity, and folktales about him were common to all Germanic peoples, including, of course, the Angles and the Saxons, who named the fourth day of the week after him. So yes, you could describe him as a ‘Viking god’, but it would be equally correct to describe him as an English god, a Dutch god, or a Bavarian god. Inadvertently or not, the Scandinavians have appropriated what is actually the common patrimony of a number of countries.

Something quite similar has happened with the concept of the ‘Nordic welfare state’. There is no exact definition of that term, and if you use it in order to denote a welfare system with particular design features – emphasis on universal (as opposed to means-tested) benefits, financing through progressive taxation rather than social insurance contributions, etc. – I’ll let you off the hook. But most of the time, the term ‘Nordic welfare state’ is used in the sense of ‘a welfare state which is exceptionally large, encompassing and progressive’. And that usage is not correct.

The graph below shows net social expenditure in high-income countries as a proportion of GDP. This is the best measure for international comparisons, because it automatically corrects for cross-country differences in the tax treatment of social transfers. Suppose in one country, the poorest X% of the population receive a tax-free income transfer of £800. In an otherwise identical country, the poorest X% receive a transfer of £1000, but the transfer is subject to an income tax payment of £200. In a comparison of gross social spending, it would appear as if the second country had a much larger welfare state. In a comparison of net spending, the countries would appear identical.

For most countries, the difference between gross and net social spending is not very large, because benefit income is usually not heavily taxed. The gross/net distinction can therefore, for a lot of purposes, be ignored as a technicality. But there are exceptions, and the Nordic countries are among them. Once transfer income is adjusted for direct taxes levied on it, the Nordics cease to be exceptional. After the adjustment, it is still not incorrect to say that the Nordic welfare states are large – but it is wrong to insinuate that welfare state largesse is a specifically Scandinavian property. It is really a property which the Nordics share with many other countries, so there is no reason to single them out in this regard.

Net social expenditure (public and publicly mandated) in % of GDP, 2011

graph

-based on OECD data


The graph shows that France and Belgium are the real Big Welfare countries, that Anglosphere countries are overrepresented at the opposite end, while the Nordics do not even form a visible cluster of their own. There is simply nothing very special about them. Some of the Mediterranean countries’ position at the high end has probably more to do with the euro crisis rather than with a deliberately adopted social model, but the broad pattern still stands.

You get a similar impression if you rank welfare states by the extent to which they reduce a country’s Gini coefficient, or by various indices of ‘progressivity’: The Nordic welfare states are very progressive and very redistributive, but not outstandingly so. These features are common to many welfare states, and there is no reason to attribute them specifically to the Nordic countries.

So why do we continue to hear eulogies for the Nordic welfare state as if it were a unique and outstanding model? Presumably, the reason is simply that this produces the desired result. People from across the political spectrum see the Nordic countries as successful economies from which a lot can be learned. “Big Government works – look at Sweden!” sounds more credible than “Big Government works – look at Italy!”. The Nordic countries are international outliers, but in a very different respect: They offer a combination of factors which makes them uniquely resilient to Big Government policies. That, however, is a topic for another blog.

Head of Political Economy

Dr Kristian Niemietz is the IEA's Editorial Director, and Head of Political Economy. Kristian studied Economics at the Humboldt Universität zu Berlin and the Universidad de Salamanca, graduating in 2007 as Diplom-Volkswirt (≈MSc in Economics). During his studies, he interned at the Central Bank of Bolivia (2004), the National Statistics Office of Paraguay (2005), and at the IEA (2006). He also studied Political Economy at King's College London, graduating in 2013 with a PhD. Kristian previously worked as a Research Fellow at the Berlin-based Institute for Free Enterprise (IUF), and taught Economics at King's College London. He is the author of the books "Socialism: The Failed Idea That Never Dies" (2019), "Universal Healthcare Without The NHS" (2016), "Redefining The Poverty Debate" (2012) and "A New Understanding of Poverty" (2011).



Newsletter Signup