Tax and Fiscal Policy

The final retreat in the fiscal stimulus debate


Which school of economic thought has been vindicated by the macroeconomic performance of the UK over the past five years? Given that economists, historians and politicians are still busy analysing the events of the 1930s and the Keynes-Hayek debate of that period, we are unlikely to get a consensus any time soon. But while Keynesians on both sides of the Atlantic (see Paul Krugman in the US and Simon Wren-Lewis here) continue to write self-congratulatory blog posts about how effective their models have been in explaining the economic recovery – usually citing each other – in the political sphere they have overwhelmingly lost the debate. Nowhere is this clearer than in the recently published Labour manifesto.

Don’t get me wrong. I’m not saying that Labour have signed themselves up to a particularly austere programme for the coming Parliament. In fact, as the Institute for Fiscal Studies outlined last week, the party’s declared aims are vague and leave plenty of room for manoeuvre.

Labour say they want to cut the deficit every year. But given that our deficit is £90bn, this could be achieved by cutting £1 annually for 90bn years. Presumably that’s why they have reinforced this commitment by promising to balance the current budget and get net debt as a proportion of GDP falling “as soon as possible in the next Parliament”.

Even then, it is not clear they really mean “as soon as possible” as you or I would understand it. Given that Labour complain that the Conservative plans entail cuts which are too harsh, presumably what they really believe is that eliminating the deficit “as soon as possible” would be dangerous for public services.

Leaving that aside, the significant thing in all this is that Labour has simply stopped making the case that government spending is good for our short-term macro-economic prospects. Yes, they are still committed to borrowing for capital spending in the next Parliament. But the justification is less the traditional Keynesian argument that such spending will stimulate demand and more about improving the productive capacity of the economy. Yes, they denounce the scale of the cuts the Conservatives plan. But this is articulated as a fear for the effects these might have on the quality of public services, not the macro-economic impact.

This marks a remarkable intellectual retreat. Perhaps it’s just a rhetorical change, but narrative matters. The Labour manifesto contains no critique of the coalition’s macroeconomic policy whatsoever. Despite years of claiming that government fiscal consolidation was “too far, too fast”, that the “savage cuts” risked double-dip and triple-dip recessions, and that the coalition “choked off” a recovery in 2010, now the only critique of the past five years from Labour seems to be that the Conservative-led government has borrowed more than it promised. For a party that, as a matter of policy, was committed to borrowing more to “support the economy”, this is bizarre.

One might have expected the party to maintain its critique of fiscal consolidation between 2010 and 2012, but to buttress it by saying that, now the economy is recovering strongly, it is appropriate to have a moderate plan to reduce the deficit. Or to say that the government had got it wrong in implementing the capital spending cuts it inherited from Labour. Or that front-loading tax rises was a mistake. But Labour now say nothing of the sort.

Instead, they have evidently seen it necessary to completely cede or ignore this debate to restore their economic credibility given the changed economic situation. While Labour’s plans would still see higher borrowing, more debt and more capital spending than the Tories, they are unwilling or unable to make the macro-economic case for such action. In the political world, Keynesians are on the retreat.

This article first appeared in City AM.

Head of Public Policy and Director, Paragon Initiative

Ryan Bourne is Head of Public Policy at the IEA and Director of The Paragon Initiative. Ryan was educated at Magdalene College, Cambridge where he achieved a double-first in Economics at undergraduate level and later an MPhil qualification. Prior to joining the IEA, Ryan worked for a year at the economic consultancy firm Frontier Economics on competition and public policy issues. After leaving Frontier in 2010, Ryan joined the Centre for Policy Studies think tank in Westminster, first as an Economics Researcher and subsequently as Head of Economic Research. There, he was responsible for writing, editing and commissioning economic reports across a broad range of areas, as well as organisation of economic-themed events and roundtables. Ryan appears regularly in the national media, including writing for The Times, the Daily Telegraph, ConservativeHome and Spectator Coffee House, and appearing on broadcast, including BBC News, Newsnight, Sky News, Jeff Randall Live, Reuters and LBC radio. He is currently a weekly columnist for CityAM.


1 thought on “The final retreat in the fiscal stimulus debate”

  1. Posted 28/04/2015 at 22:29 | Permalink

    It seems unsatisfactory if one’s only (or main) criticism of the coalition government’s performance with respect to the deficit and the national debt is to assert (correctly) that the actual result has turned out to be a lot different from what the Chancellor of the Exchequer predicted back in 2010 in the post-election budget.
    Suppose Osborne had predicted, in the 2010 budget, that the annual deficit would continue to run well above 3 per cent of national income for the foreseeable future and that net new borrowing would amount to hundreds of billions of pounds. He would certainly have earned a much higher score for ‘accuracy’, but so what? Unless the Labour opposition is arguing that Osborne ought to have raised taxes/cut spending much more fiercely than he actually did, all they seem to be saying is that economic growth ‘ought’ to have been much higher than it actually was. I call that the Eliza Doolittle approach to analysis — ‘wouldn’t it be luvverly?’ Incidentally, may I remind younger readers of Ralph Harris’s definition of a forecast: “A pretence of knowing what would have happened if what did happen hadn’t.”

Comments are closed.


Newsletter Signup