Energy and Environment

How Britain can fix its Nimby problem


SUGGESTED

Government and Institutions
Uncategorized
The coalition is considering plans to loosen the rules governing the development of new infrastructure, fracking sites, and potentially housing, to facilitate investment. The specifics are not yet clear, but they seem to be on the right track. The potential of UK shale, for example, is huge – if it can be realised. New research by EY this week is expected to reinforce the existing evidence that fracking will create tens of thousands of jobs and drive billions of pounds of investment.

What is guaranteed, however, is that the usual suspects will accuse the government of ‘riding roughshod over local communities’. Such claims are misguided – but they also show why the coalition’s plans fail to address the systemic flaw in Britain’s approach. There is a disconnect between the costs and benefits of economic activity at the local level. Nimbyism will remain a permanent fixture unless it is tackled.

There are economic activities that deliver so-called positive spillover effects, like regeneration, to the area in which they are conducted. They therefore benefit a wide range of residents. Other activities, however, also have costs, like increased traffic, noise, disruption, or a loss of green space. Finding the ‘optimal’ level and composition of economic activity, therefore, is a matter of a cost-benefit analysis, and sensible decisions can only be made when costs and benefits are properly aligned. But in Britain they are not, as can be shown using a simple thought experiment.

Suppose there are two towns, Nimbyville and Progresstown. The latter takes a permissive approach to economic activity, while Nimbyville rejects anything that has mildly unpleasant side effects. As a result, the two towns diverge. Progresstown has airports, power stations, motorways, fracking, and housing developments. Nimbyville refuses permission for any such project. Neither is better or worse: Nimbyville, which has a housing shortage, lower incomes and fewer jobs, looks with envy at the dynamism of Progresstown. The latter’s residents admire Nimbyville’s tranquillity.

Then suppose Progresstown and Nimbyville enter a fiscal union. For Nimbyville, this is hugely lucrative. It soon enjoys the same standard of public services as Progresstown, but without the annoying economic activity that finances them. Nimbyville also requires high levels of spending on unemployment benefits, and on housing benefit for those who are priced out of the market. But since that bill is now sent to Progresstown, Nimbyville no longer needs to levy high taxes.

Consequently, Nimbyville adopts an even stronger anti-growth stance, since it no longer pays for the resulting costs. And Progresstown becomes a lot like Nimbyville. What’s the point in tolerating all those grubby, noisy, unsightly activities if the proceeds are shipped elsewhere? Soon enough, all towns become like Nimbyville. Central government may still push for the pro-development policies that once characterised Progresstown, but it will be accused of ‘riding roughshod over local communities’. Sound familiar?

The real solution is to make those who obstruct development pay the cost of Nimbyism, and for those who embrace it to reap the benefits. Local fiscal autonomy, and tax competition between authorities, is the way to go.

This article was originally published by City AM.

Follow @K_Niemietz on Twitter.

Head of Political Economy

Dr Kristian Niemietz is the IEA's Editorial Director, and Head of Political Economy. Kristian studied Economics at the Humboldt Universität zu Berlin and the Universidad de Salamanca, graduating in 2007 as Diplom-Volkswirt (≈MSc in Economics). During his studies, he interned at the Central Bank of Bolivia (2004), the National Statistics Office of Paraguay (2005), and at the IEA (2006). He also studied Political Economy at King's College London, graduating in 2013 with a PhD. Kristian previously worked as a Research Fellow at the Berlin-based Institute for Free Enterprise (IUF), and taught Economics at King's College London. He is the author of the books "Socialism: The Failed Idea That Never Dies" (2019), "Universal Healthcare Without The NHS" (2016), "Redefining The Poverty Debate" (2012) and "A New Understanding of Poverty" (2011).


2 thoughts on “How Britain can fix its Nimby problem”

  1. Posted 27/04/2014 at 12:40 | Permalink

    Fracking is relatively easy. Just return to the pre-1930s position of the people who live over the stuff having the property rights. If Shell wants to extract it, it has to pay for the right. Of course, there are issues to do with hold-outs, negotiating with large numbers who have different preferences and so on, but that should be the starting point.

  2. Posted 27/04/2014 at 15:46 | Permalink

    Is there a way of capturing part of the large increase in land values that results from the grant of planning permission to fund benefits for people and communities who would be affected by new housing developments? Funding could also be found in this way for new facilities such as schools and doctors’ surgeries.

    Another possibility would be to link the relaxation of planning restrictions with improved building standards including, for example, larger rooms and higher ceilings in new houses, plus better quality building materials. If the quality of new developments on former greenfield sites is clearly superior to that of the typical houses we have been building in recent decades, that could spark yet more interest in new housebuilding.

Comments are closed.


Newsletter Signup