“Harmful” tax competition: new actors, same old plot
SUGGESTED
The latest episode in this seemingly never-ending serial is the US government’s increased pressure on American firms and citizens living and/or investing in Asia. Hong Kong and Singapore have taken over the role of the tax revenue thieves previously played by Switzerland and Liechtenstein, and the US has taken over the role of the Franco-German high-tax Sheriff.
The story is a bit thin for those who remember the last series, because the plot is basically the same: financial institutions in Hong Kong and Singapore are being pressurised to provide financial information on US taxpayers. The governments of Hong Kong and Singapore are put on a blacklist of “uncooperative” partners. The new twist, however, consists of the American government’s proposal to extend US tax liability to US citizens’ investment income generated in Asia, even before it is repatriated.
Tax competition is not particularly popular, either among governments, international organisations, or anti-globalisation activists. Its opponents claim that tax competition is a zero-sum game in the short term, and a race to the bottom in the long-term. By cutting taxes, it is asserted, country A attracts investment, but only at the expense of country B. Total welfare is constant. In the long-term, governments in A and B are forced to undercut each other’s tax rates, and thus lose the ability to fund valuable public services.
There are at least two fallacies involved here. Firstly, in so far as citizens really receive valuable services for their tax money, tax rates do not represent a competitive disadvantage. If country A can only afford lower taxes than country B by leaving its court system and police force hopelessly underfunded, A will neither attract investors nor skilled workers from B. But if taxes in B are higher because B’s government funds a lot of projects that its citizens do not value enough, or because it incurs expenses that merely benefit one subset of B’s population at the expense of another, or if it insists on providing services that A’s citizens buy more cheaply in the private sector, the picture changes. Tax competition is not a threat to the provision of public goods people cherish, but it constrains governments from taking over ever more tasks that should be performed by private companies, or not at all.
Secondly, tax competition is not a zero-sum game. If it acts to drive down harmful taxation of productive activities such as saving, work and entrepreneurship, then more of these activities can take place. Instead of country A benefiting at the expense of country B, it is more accurate to think of the citizens in A and B benefiting, because government officials in A and B have to moderate themselves.
There is therefore no such thing as “harmful tax competition”. Tax competition is an effective and necessary means of protecting individuals against the insatiable tax appetites of their own governments.
8 thoughts on ““Harmful” tax competition: new actors, same old plot”
Comments are closed.
In his Hobart Paper, ‘The Benefits of Tax Competition’, Richard Teather quotes from James Bartholomew and Angus Maddison in arriving at the following table showing GDP per capita, in constant 1990 $, for the highly-taxed United Kingdom and low-tax Hong Kong:
1950 1973 1999
UK 6,907 12,022 19,030
Hong Kong 2,218 7,104 20,352
Even if one’s objective were to maximise the government’s tax revenue, it seems it might make more sense, in the long run, to confiscate a small share of a fast-growing national income than a much higher share of a much more slowly-growing national income.
In his Hobart Paper, ‘The Benefits of Tax Competition’, Richard Teather quotes from James Bartholomew and Angus Maddison in arriving at the following table showing GDP per capita, in constant 1990 $, for the highly-taxed United Kingdom and low-tax Hong Kong:
1950 1973 1999
UK 6,907 12,022 19,030
Hong Kong 2,218 7,104 20,352
Even if one’s objective were to maximise the government’s tax revenue, it seems it might make more sense, in the long run, to confiscate a small share of a fast-growing national income than a much higher share of a much more slowly-growing national income.
Another good example is Ireland. Notwithstanding the recent difficulties of its financial sector, it has managed to overtake the UK in terms of GDP per head through a policy of relatively low taxes, particularly taxes on businesses. In the long run this policy has meant higher tax revenues and better public services than the high-tax, low-growth option.
Another good example is Ireland. Notwithstanding the recent difficulties of its financial sector, it has managed to overtake the UK in terms of GDP per head through a policy of relatively low taxes, particularly taxes on businesses. In the long run this policy has meant higher tax revenues and better public services than the high-tax, low-growth option.
I guess the time preference rate is the critical issue. A government with a ‘dynastic’ mindset would prefer the Hong Kong option, an ‘impatient’ government the high-tax one.
It could also be that some governments value influence more than money per se. In this case, their relative share in the economy would be more important to them than the amount of money at their disposal.
After all, the Swiss government is probably the least powerful one in the world, despite all the francs they have.
I guess the time preference rate is the critical issue. A government with a ‘dynastic’ mindset would prefer the Hong Kong option, an ‘impatient’ government the high-tax one.
It could also be that some governments value influence more than money per se. In this case, their relative share in the economy would be more important to them than the amount of money at their disposal.
After all, the Swiss government is probably the least powerful one in the world, despite all the francs they have.
‘Government’ is not monolithic (is ‘polylithic’ the right description?). So politicians, craving re-election above all, might be short-termist, with a high interest rate, while civil servants might be long-termist, with a low interest rate. I’m not sure that politicians would always dominate.
‘Government’ is not monolithic (is ‘polylithic’ the right description?). So politicians, craving re-election above all, might be short-termist, with a high interest rate, while civil servants might be long-termist, with a low interest rate. I’m not sure that politicians would always dominate.