Tax and Fiscal Policy

IEA Debate: Should Capital Gains Tax be abolished?


The Chancellor has asked the Office for Tax Simplification to undertake a review of Capital Gains Tax to ‘ensure the system is fit for purpose’ and to look again at how capital gains are taxed compared to other types of income. But should he go further and simply abolish Capital Gains Tax completely?

Philip Booth, the IEA’s Senior Academic Fellow, says YES

The Institute for Fiscal Studies was founded as a response to the 1965 budget in which Capital Gains Tax was introduced. One of the founders was IEA author John Chown. The group who founded the body regarded that budget as half-baked. No amount of sitting in the oven in the last 55 years has brought the capital gains tax to fully-cooked status.

The argument is regularly made that the rates of Capital Gains Tax should be brought into line with income tax in order to remove the incentive to turn income into capital gains. This is a fallacious argument. Instead the tax should largely be largely abolished.

Perhaps the most pertinent example we can use is capital gains tax on company shares. Share prices can go up when companies retain profits, thus raising the value of assets in respect of each share. They also rise when investors anticipate higher profits in the future. So-called unicorn shares often see very high valuations before they make profits for this reason. In both these situations, the profits that companies have earned and retained or will learn in the future are taxed at the time they are earned through the corporation tax system. The valuation of a unicorn company already reflects taxes that will be paid on profits in the future. Capital Gains Tax is an unjust double tax. 

Of course, share prices also fluctuate because of changes in interest rates, changes in risk, monetary booms and busts and speculation. But these factors do not lead share prices to rise systematically. The downward trend in long-term interest rates is causing high valuations relative to expected dividend levels at the moment. But the next 20 years might see that trend reversed. When we buy an asset or a property, we buy into a long-term income stream. There is no reason to tax those owners who happen to buy into an asset before prices rise (and then have to provide reliefs to those who buy before prices fall).

There is a range of situations in which Capital Gains Tax is charged where no other taxes may be due. This includes first and second owner-occupied homes. But the underlying problem here is that we do not have a good system for taxing imputed income from owner-occupied property. Taxing capital gains is a very bad way to deal with this.

It is true that much energy can go into disguising income as capital gains. However, HMRC is already wise to that. The best way to deal with this problem is to ensure that income disguised as capital gains is taxed as income – at the point at which income accrues. Perhaps HMRC should re-double its efforts in these areas (and perhaps the Capital Gains Tax makes HMRC lazy in so doing).

It is possible that there are some assets such as paintings and antiques which are intrinsically non-income-bearing on which a capital gains tax could be levied. But, even here I am unconvinced. We should not be taxing transactions. To do so is complex, inefficient and also unfair given the absence of any indexation of capital values for inflation. Raising Capital Gains Tax rates will probably lead to a drop in revenue given the complexities of the tax. Indeed, if we keep this problematic tax, one thing is clear: its optimal rates are much lower than our current rates of income tax.

Julian Jessop, IEA Economics Fellow, says NO

Capital Gains Tax is a bad tax, but then most are. There are three main argument against its abolition.

First, it raises a meaningful amount of revenue – about £10 billion a year. These days that may not be a huge sum in the context of the public finances. Nonetheless, it is still money that would have to be found elsewhere.

Put another way, £10 billion is roughly the entire annual budget of the Ministry of Justice, which pays for civil and criminal courts, prisons and the probation system in England and Wales. Or this sum could be used to fund other tax cuts that would have more obvious benefits, such as reducing the burden on lower-paid workers and on the businesses that employ them.

Second, and at least as importantly, Capital Gains Tax protects other revenues that might be lost if people can artificially reduce their tax bills by converting income into capital gains. As a starting point, the principle of ‘tax neutrality’ suggests that these gains should be taxed at the same rate as other forms of income, whether from savings (dividends or interest) or from employment.

Third, Capital Gains Tax is a relatively progressive tax, mainly paid by the better off. Abolition would therefore lead to windfall gains for those who already have the ‘broadest shoulders’ and further undermine confidence in the tax system.

Of course, Capital Gains Tax itself can distort incentives. In particular, it affects the timing of decisions to buy and sell assets, because it is only charged when a transaction takes place. But most existing taxes create significant distortions, unless we ditch the lot in favour of the sort of pure expenditure tax advocated in the Meade Report.

Similarly, many resources are undoubtedly wasted on ‘tax planning’ to minimise liability for Capital Gains Tax. But if Capital Gains Tax did not exist at all, even more effort would be devoted to finding new ways to ensure income is taken in the form of capital gains.

There are some valid concerns about ‘double taxation’, especially when gains in asset prices reflect expectations of increases in income that will be taxed separately anyway. However, this is not a convincing argument for getting rid of Capital Gains Tax completely. Instead, it is an argument for continuing to charge Capital Gains Tax at a lower rate on gains which might already be subject to other taxes, now or in the future, so that the combined rate of all taxes is the same as that on alternative forms of income.

That said, the current system of Capital Gains Tax is definitely a mess. It has a myriad of different rates, allowances and exemptions, and messy interactions with other taxes (notably inheritance tax). It is certainly crying out for ‘simplification’. But ‘abolition’ would be a step too far.


1 thought on “IEA Debate: Should Capital Gains Tax be abolished?”

  1. Posted 22/07/2020 at 09:21 | Permalink

    Surely better to abolish corporation (profits) tax and align CGT and income tax ?

Comments are closed.


Newsletter Signup