Economic Theory

Tomorrow 3.0


SUGGESTED

Trade, Development, and Immigration

There have been two enormous “revolutions” in human history. The first was the Neolithic, or the wide scale switch from a nomadic hunter-gatherer lifestyle to fixed agriculture. The second was the industrial, or the wide scale concentration of production in processes that took advantage of division of labour and capital-intensive work. The most salient features of both revolutions was unprecedented expansion: after the Neolithic revolution, cities developed and population increased in ways that transformed the landscape.

After the industrial revolution, production processes developed in ways that, within just a few generations, afforded a set of consumer items for the poor that were unattainable even for the wealthy just a century earlier. In both revolutions, individual liberty, nutrition, and hygiene all suffered, for many people. But the longer term consequences were that many more people lived on earth, they lived longer, and they had better lives. The increase in population and life expectation after industrialisaton in Britain, for example, was extraordinary (see table).

England and Wales population growth

Date Life expectation at birth for males (years) Population
1850 41 18 million
1880 47 26 million
1910 56 36 million
1940 72 41 million

 

The key reason is summarised by Adam Smith. It happened because of the division of labour and the benefits from expanding the horizon of economic co-operation from families, to villages, to nations, and then to the entire globe. This is so obvious that it escapes our attention most of the time. In a tribe of 100, there may be someone who is skilled at beating bones on a rock. In a clan of 1,000, there may someone who can play a flute while others pluck a string on a piece of wood. In a city of 100,000 there are chamber orchestras. And in a city of 1 million there is a symphony orchestra with specialised instruments and professional musicians. The next revolution will be like that, too. In fact, it is like that already.

The Sharing Revolution

Because of division of labour, I can specialise in a narrow (though productive) activity, because I can rely on other people to specialise in other narrow (though productive) activities, making everything I need, from food to a nice woollen coat. But until now this system has relied on ownership. We ended up with far more stuff than any of us actually needed, or could use. We store the stuff in closets, garages, and self-store containers.

Why? Why do we own, rather than rent, so much stuff? The answer is transactions costs. When I need an electric saw, I don’t rent one. I go to my garage and find my electric circular saw. I only use that saw two or three times a year. But I still own one. On the other hand, when I fly to Oklahoma to work on a video programme or give lectures, I don’t buy a car; I hire one. Why do I own a saw, but hire cars?

The reason is that it has paid some entrepreneur to sell reductions in transactions costs, in the form of software. People can enter all their information, including preferences and payment information, into a database. When I get off the plane, I get a text: “Your car is in space A39”. So I can go straight from aeroplane to car. I just turn the key – which is already in the car – and drive to the gate, where they print my contract and check my ID. Students in Canada no longer need to own cars even if they want 24-hour-a-day access to four wheels. They simply join Student Car Share for about £30.

This kind of approach, combined with the kind of delivery service provided by Uber or Lyft, will soon revolutionise almost every aspect of our lives. As transactions costs fall much of the “stuff” we now own will be rented or shared. Some of us will become “sellers” and some “renters,” but overall each of us will need to possess far, far less stuff at any given time.

From Owning to Renting, From Companies to People

The reason I own a power saw, instead of renting one, is that the transactions costs of renting are prohibitive. Suppose I could open an app, choose “power saw,” and press “rent”. A driver somewhere picks up a saw from a hardware store, and conveys it to my security-coded delivery pod by the street. My phone beeps:  “saw delivered”. I go out, get the saw, use it, and return it to the pod. The pod tells another driver (no particular driver, just whoever is closest; I don’t know who it is, and I don’t need to know) that there is a package to be picked up.

With sufficient density, the cost of the rental would be no more than $3 or $4.  And there is no standing in queues for forms to fill out.  Best of all, I would get a commercial quality saw for the period that I needed to use it. The relative benefit of “rent versus buy” is determined by transactions costs – a subject about which Ronald Coase taught us so much.

Most people are now familiar with Uber. This illustrates two points. The fall in transactions costs have made renting car time much, much cheaper – anybody can rent to anybody. But there are also huge advantages from the division of labour involved. For many people, it may be cheaper to use Uber to take them to work than it is to own a car – and then they can work whilst somebody else drives. And millions of people who have not got great academic qualifications now have a market opening for earning money whilst driving other people around.

The biggest change in the software platform-driven revolution is that people will skip companies, except as middlemen. We are already used to this for AirBnB and Uber, both of which provide access to privately-owned services (rooms and rides, respectively) for private citizens. All the software does is provide information, take care of security (through ratings and reputation), and process the transaction (removing most of the risk of robbery or reneging).

But there are hundreds of other examples, relating to stuff you may not have thought of renting. One company, Spinlister, brings together people who own but are not using for a day or a week or more, bikes, surf equipment and ski equipment. All three of these items are relatively durable, sometimes not used for long periods and expensive. Some households have more stuff than they can use. Other households need stuff for short periods. With high transactions costs, the choices were either to buy (expensive in terms of cash and storage) or do without. If an entrepreneur can sell the reduction in transactions cost through a software platform, private individuals will make much more intensive use of the stuff we already have.

Shortly, the result will be that many of us will have a lot less stuff. I won’t need to own a laptop, a bike, a car, luggage… and maybe even clothes. A company called RentTheRunway rents “unlimited clothing and accessories” for $99 per month.  It’s not really unlimited, of course. Customers can only have one of each item per category at a time. But when you are finished with the dress/shoes/purse you send them back.  RentTheRunway takes care of the UPS shipping, and the dry cleaning.

The Downside

The good news is that we will all need a lot less stuff, to own or to store. The bad news is that… well, that’s the bad news. An economy geared toward making new stuff, in which entrepreneurs have always been focused on making new products or on making more old products more cheaply will be shaken to its foundations.

Instead of 90 million power saws sitting in closets and garages, we will only need 10 million. We will need far fewer cars, fewer bikes, fewer just about everything. Some people, probably a lot of people, will lose their jobs. And they will not get new jobs, at least jobs in the sense that we understand them. They may work “gigs” or temporary periods as part of teams, much like the construction industry or Broadway plays operate now.

Is this good or bad? As in the previous two revolutions, that hardly matters, because the economic logic is inescapable: it is just going to happen. Still, I think it is fair to say that for most people the effect will be positive. Cities will not need parking spaces. Houses will not need garages or as many cupboards. Energy use in manufacturing, and the amount of waste produced from packaging and discarding broken or unused products will plummet. Some people will lose their jobs and perhaps have lower nominal wages. But prices are likely to fall even faster, implying an actual increase in real wages. And many jobs and opportunities will be created. Many Uber drivers are older people who really value the socialising and the income it generates. Many who rent out Airbnb rooms will be single people or widows who might be capital-rich and income-poor. And the remarkable thing about a market economy, of course, is that we can never know what opportunities it will create in the future.

But the winning formula is, less stuff, less strain on the environment, better use of the stuff we have, and many prices close to zero. Tomorrow 3.0 is closer than you think.

Prof Michael Munger is a Professor of Political Science, Public Policy and Economics at Duke University, North Carolina. This article was written for EA Magazine.



2 thoughts on “Tomorrow 3.0”

  1. Posted 05/02/2016 at 14:22 | Permalink

    The population figures for England and Wales are even more striking if one goes back another 100 years. In 1750 the population of England and Wales was probably only 7 million. By 2050 it could be ten times as many. I forget who it was who said: ‘Trends go on until they stop.’

  2. Posted 08/02/2016 at 22:04 | Permalink

    (1) Re: Uber — hiring a car and driver is generally going to be significantly more expensive than just renting a car. So there’s clearly some level of use where the money saved by not owning a car is less than the aggregate wages you will pay to the driver(s) over and above the pro-rated cost of the car. So unless you are in the position where you really can measurably increase your income with the time spent in the passenger seat, the point at which you might as well own a car and drive yourself is probably lower than you think.

    (2) Re: the saw — your $3-$4 estimate is way low. Is there any reason to expect that the one-way fare for a saw chauffeur will be less than the Uber base fare of $5-$7 at the cheapest? I live between five and ten minutes away from a Lowes in the suburbs, so it’s unlikely that you’ll have the “density” to have the saw depot any closer to my house than the Lowes, and I certainly wouldn’t make that trip for less than five bucks. And, for the record, Lowes actually DOES rent tools — with a daily rate between $25 and $65. I can’t see how adding a fleet of independent drivers is going to get that rate down under five bucks per rental.

    (And, of course, demand is not uniform. That saw will likely have 5x “surge pricing” on a nice Saturday morning, and the vast majority of saws will be stting idle at 10PM on a Tuesday.)

    (3) This future seems to be one in which there are a lot of cars flying around the roads doing very minor errands. This model has the exact same transaction costs as the model in which you jump into your car, drive to the hardware store to pick up a rental saw, use it, and then return it–except you’re paying those costs in cash instead of in your own time/effort/gas.

Comments are closed.


Newsletter Signup