Labour Market

The apprenticeships levy and apprenticeship targets: the economics of the cargo cult


SUGGESTED

Lifestyle Economics
Trade, Development, and Immigration
Real apprenticeships provide skills which workers can take to other employers and obtain a wage higher than they would have earned otherwise. Historically, they were paid for by binding young employees (with legal sanctions for breaking the agreement) to work for a fixed period with very low pay, and often with an upfront payment from the family or sponsor of the youngsters.

In modern conditions, where restrictions on employee movement are virtually non-existent, where minimum wage legislation (albeit with a lower rate for some apprentices) puts a floor on pay, and when the costs of many types of training are beyond family resources, a shortage of apprentices can arise. The obvious government intervention, if this is a problem, is to provide income-contingent loans, as we do for undergraduates, and allow young people to look for apprenticeships which suit them.

Governments like ours don’t think about apprenticeships as rational career investments by individuals, but rather as the key to higher productivity for UK plc. Anecdotal arguments about shortages of highly-skilled workers are quoted, but the argument that 3m apprentices by 2020 will produce big productivity gains is really the economics of the cargo cult.

Recent governments have spent a lot of money subsidising apprenticeships: in England, £1.6bn in 2014-15. In an odd way, too: a government-funded organisation, the Skills Funding Agency, has contracted with “providers” (such as further education colleges or other private organisations) to sign up a certain number of employers.

Employers have been fairly passive in this set-up, with much paperwork and assessment of apprentices being dealt with by providers. Formal training programmes relate to standards laid down by the Skills Funding Agency and other external bodies.

The incentive for providers has been to generate large numbers of low-level apprenticeships, which are short (some only a few months), cheap and easy to complete: payments are made for successful completion. In 2013-14, only 2 per cent of apprentice starts were at the higher level, the equivalent of most German apprenticeships. Two-thirds of the 440,000 starts were at the lowest (misleadingly termed “intermediate”) level. Rather than new apprentice jobs being provided, some employers were simply rebadging existing staff, as in the notorious case where over 20,000 existing Morrisons supermarket workers, 88 per cent of whom were over the age of 25, were enrolled as “apprentices”.

The government plans a new Delivery Board, 150 new “employer-led standards” (no doubt written largely by the usual suspects, consultants and redundant lecturers) and so on. But it’s still the same mindset.

Given budgetary constraints, it’s easy to understand the rationale for offloading the cost of apprenticeships onto employers, through the new apprenticeships levy. But the focus on apprenticeship numbers is nonsense. The sort of high-level manufacturing, construction and technology apprenticeships which ministers fantasise about can only ever, given the structure of UK industry, realistically run into the low tens of thousands. To make up the numbers and reduce firms’ costs, we will just get variations on the Morrisons story.

This isn’t only a wasteful policy. There will be other negative consequences. In practice, as the OBR recognises, the apprenticeships levy acts as a crude payroll tax. Although such taxes hit profits in the short run, they are eventually passed on in reduced wages and/or reduced employment, probably – paradoxically – for the lower-skilled. This is, then, a tax on shelf-stackers which is based on a fundamentally flawed approach.

Prof Len Shackleton is a Visiting Fellow at the IEA, and professor of economics at the University of Buckingham. This article first appeared in City AM.

Editorial and Research Fellow

Len Shackleton is an Editorial and Research Fellow at the IEA and Professor of Economics at the University of Buckingham. He was previously Dean of the Royal Docks Business School at the University of East London and prior to that was Dean of the Westminster Business School. He has also taught at Queen Mary, University of London and worked as an economist in the Civil Service. His research interests are primarily in the economics of labour markets. He has worked with many think tanks, most closely with the Institute of Economic Affairs, where he is an Economics Fellow. He edits the journal Economic Affairs, which is co-published by the IEA and the University of Buckingham.


2 thoughts on “The apprenticeships levy and apprenticeship targets: the economics of the cargo cult”

  1. Posted 02/12/2015 at 13:09 | Permalink

    “The sort of high-level manufacturing, construction and technology apprenticeships which ministers fantasise about can only ever, given the structure of UK industry, realistically run into the low tens of thousands”.

    Can you clarify how the structure of UK industry hinders the development of high-level manufacturing, construction and technology apprenticeships? I didn’t pick this up from the text of your post (apologies if it is self evident).

  2. Posted 07/12/2015 at 19:41 | Permalink

    I simply meant that we do not have the scale of operation in these sectors to support very large numbers of high-quality apprenticeships. Even doubling the numbers of high-level apprenticeships would amount to a small fraction of the target of 3 million.

Comments are closed.


Newsletter Signup