Society and Culture

Communitarianism: the art of passing off trivial clichés as profound wisdoms


Communitarianism is on the rise. The Left has its “Blue Labour” project, and writers like Giles Fraser and Paul Embery. The Right has its “One Nation Conservatism” project, and writers like Nick Timothy and Tim Montgomery. They differ in emphasis, but the commonalities outweigh the differences. It appeals to both right-wingers looking for an alternative to economic liberalism, and to left-wingers looking for an alternative to “woke” hyper-moralism.

What is communitarianism? Communitarians would probably define themselves as people who recognise the importance of community and social relations, but that is a bit like saying that environmentalists are people who care about the environment, or that feminists are people who believe in gender equality. Defining a political outlook in motherhood-and-apple-pie terms, so that you could not disagree with it without coming across like a complete psychopath, is not particularly useful. Apart from Britain’s four or five Randians, everybody recognises the importance of community and social relations. (And presumably, Britain’s four or five Randians tacitly recognise it too.)

In practice, communitarianism is little else but a knee-jerk anti-liberalism. Communitarians define themselves in opposition to an imaginary hyper-materialistic, hyper-individualistic liberal, who sees life as no more than a long string of financial transactions, and society as no more than a bunch of isolated individuals who happen to live side by side. Communitarians never identify any specific person who actually holds that view, which is not too surprising, because, apart from Britain’s aforementioned four or five Randians (who, on a bad day, might come a little bit close to that caricature), no such person exists.

And yet, these fictitious people are absolutely central to the self-image of communitarians. Communitarians derive a great sense of unwarranted smugness and imaginary superiority from it. If you define yourself in opposition to a worldview which is, in obvious ways, reductionist and one-dimensional, you can constantly congratulate yourself on how your own worldview is so much richer, so much more well-rounded, and so much more nuanced than that of your imaginary opponents.

But is it not true that economic liberals tend to talk a lot more about GDP, productivity, inflation, unemployment, labour force participation, exchange rates etc. than they talk about the value of community and the search for meaning in life? Does this not suggest that their view of society is somewhat one-sided?

The answer is no. It is obviously true that most people are not just striving for material prosperity, but also seek a sense of purpose and meaning, which can come from being a member of a community, from strong social bonds, from a sense of place, from an attachment to a town, a region or a country. However, this is such an obvious, and such a trivial observation that it is simply not worth explicitly stating it. You, dear reader, have chosen to read this blog, when you had thousands of others to choose from, alongside news outlets, podcasts, vidcasts, or cat videos. Thank you for that! I’m not going to repay you by boring you with clichés, trivialities and truisms.

Further, communitarians also labour under the misapprehension that liberal economists somehow have the power to change social norms. It is, of course, easy to think of examples of social developments that might raise GDP, but also weaken social ties. Other things equal, a society where people are geographically mobile, and prepared to move to where the high-paying jobs are, will be richer than a society where people are more attached to their place of origin. But in such a society, it may also be harder to put down deep roots, and form stable social relations. Other things equal, a society with high levels of job mobility, where people are constantly looking out for better options and are prepared to change jobs frequently, will be richer than a society where people are more attached to their workplace. But in such a society, workplace relations may also be shallower. Other things equal, a society where people put their careers ahead of everything else, even if it adversely affects their family life, will be richer than a society where people prioritise their family life. But there are obvious downsides to this. And so on. It is true that where such trade-offs exist, economic statistics will not capture those non-material aspects.

But this is not a problem, because they don’t need to. Liberal economists have no influence on what people value, and seek no such influence. We don’t make people move places. We don’t make people change jobs. We don’t make people prioritise their careers over other things.

If you value the community spirit of a small town in rural Wales more highly than the job prospects of the English Southeast, or if you value the collegiality of your current workplace more highly than the better pay you could earn elsewhere, or if you turn down a promotion because you would rather spend more time with your family – that’s great. There’s not a single economist in the world, liberal or otherwise, who would tell you that you are doing anything wrong. (And even if there were, why would you care about some random person’s opinion?)

Communitarians are really just channelling the old left-wing trope that “capitalism” somehow makes people more materialistic, and that supporters of capitalism are therefore supporters of materialistic values. This is false. Capitalism allows you to pursue material ambitions, just as it allows you to pursue communitarian values, or something in between, or something else entirely. It’s up to you. Don’t blame “the system” if other people don’t make the choices you think they should make.

The main problem with communitarianism, though, is in its policy implications. Communitarians are often a bit vague about what kind of policies they actually want to see. This could barely be otherwise, because while it is easy to talk about community, rootedness etc. in soundbite format, at the end of the day, the state cannot “make” a society more cohesive. What would a communitarian policy platform look like? Mandatory attendance at community centre events? A system of local residence permits, like in the former Soviet Union, so that people don’t stray too far away from where they were born? Ban the retail sale of alcoholic drinks, so that people are forced to socialise at the pub?

Since communitarians do not have much of a policy agenda of their own, they usually stick to abstract waffle about “investing in communities”. And herein lies the danger. I’m a classical liberal, so I’m naturally more sceptical of government action than at least 95% of the population. But even if you don’t share that general scepticism, I hope we can at least agree that government action is usually at its worst in areas where we have no clear metric of what constitutes “success”, and what constitutes “failure”. Under those circumstances, there can be no scrutiny, and no accountability.

That is why, even if I had greater sympathy for communitarianism in principle, I would not want the government to get involved in any community-building projects. It would just be a licence for activists to push their own pet projects, because if you look for it, you can always find a way to claim that your project is somehow “vital” for “the social fabric” of the community. More, you could never criticise any such project, because you would just be dismissed as a bean-counting philistine, who knows the price of everything and the value of nothing.

And that, in a nutshell, is what communitarianism is. It is a crude “anti-economism”. Communitarianism is the pretence that trivial clichés are profound wisdoms, and that an unwillingness to engage with economic arguments makes you an especially highbrow thinker.

 

Head of Political Economy

Dr Kristian Niemietz is the IEA's Editorial Director, and Head of Political Economy. Kristian studied Economics at the Humboldt Universität zu Berlin and the Universidad de Salamanca, graduating in 2007 as Diplom-Volkswirt (≈MSc in Economics). During his studies, he interned at the Central Bank of Bolivia (2004), the National Statistics Office of Paraguay (2005), and at the IEA (2006). He also studied Political Economy at King's College London, graduating in 2013 with a PhD. Kristian previously worked as a Research Fellow at the Berlin-based Institute for Free Enterprise (IUF), and taught Economics at King's College London. He is the author of the books "Socialism: The Failed Idea That Never Dies" (2019), "Universal Healthcare Without The NHS" (2016), "Redefining The Poverty Debate" (2012) and "A New Understanding of Poverty" (2011).


3 thoughts on “Communitarianism: the art of passing off trivial clichés as profound wisdoms”

  1. Posted 14/02/2020 at 10:13 | Permalink

    A nicely argued piece that deftly skewers its target. I think you miss one of the key claims of Communitarianism though. Liberal economics shows us how to be the richest we can be, and, as you rightly point out, that is simply one choice we can make, either as a nation or an individual. The argument the Communitarians make however is that if some or most pursue the maximise wealth, economic route, the rest have to as well. They would cite the impact on house prices in London of lots of Welsh go-getters moving there perhaps, or the cost of vacations during school holidays – the pursuit of wealth above all else by some pushes up the prices of scare resources for all. I am unsure whether to see this as essentially middle-class bleating over lost position and privilege or a real problem. Perhaps at root the is some truth to the idea that if some people pursue wealth relentlessly, we are all forced to pursue it to some degree?

  2. Posted 14/02/2020 at 12:43 | Permalink

    “If you value the community spirit of a small town in rural Wales more highly than the job prospects of the English Southeast, or if you value the collegiality of your current workplace more highly than the better pay you could earn elsewhere, or if you turn down a promotion because you would rather spend more time with your family – that’s great. There’s not a single economist in the world, liberal or otherwise, who would tell you that you are doing anything wrong. (And even if there were, why would you care about some random person’s opinion?) ”

    That’s a bit astonishing, given the last few years of economists waterboarding those who favour controls on immigration in the hopes of preserving tight-knit communities. If you favour that then liberal economists would scream at you for supposedly reducing the economic growth trajectory by a tiny amount that, never being experienced is never missed. And if you don’t live your life according to the opinions of some random person with accreditation then you are a sub-human Neanderthal knuckle-dragger who doesn’t believe in experts.

  3. Posted 04/03/2020 at 18:00 | Permalink

    I suspect if you tell a ‘communitarian’ that you voted for Brexit, many of them would instantly respond with “But that will reduce GDP by 0.8%pa, why would anyone want to do that?”

Comments are closed.


SIGN UP FOR IEA EMAILS